THE
CASE FOR REDISTRIBUTIVE LIBERALISM
James
Stodder,
(written
in the Journal Economic
Systems, March 1998
Published
by the Osteuropa Institut,
Any policy mixing market liberalization with
egalitarian redistribution may seem unbalanced, even self-contradictory. In
fact, there is an important tradition of "redistributive liberalism"
associated with the growth of capitalist relations, going back at least to the
redistribution of lands in the English Civil War and French Revolution (Schmidt
1997).
In the mid-19th century, John
Stuart Mill, a founder of the Liberal Party in
Every full grown man
or woman ... would be secured in the unfettered use and disposal of his or her
bodily and mental faculties; and the instruments of production, the land and
tools, would be divided fairly among them, so that all might start, in respect
to outward appliances, on equal terms. (Book
II, Chapter 1, "On Property")
So while the question of "the least
growth inhibiting redistribution" posits a tradeoff between equality and
growth, Mill, Bentham, and other liberals considered
an egalitarian distribution of wealth important for justice and for
growth in what we now call "human capital." (Mill did not argue,
however, for the equalization of incomes ex post.) This theme is
consistent throughout what became, for the English-speaking world, the standard
economic textbook of the late 19th century (Riley 1994, xviii).
The
neoclassical model of the 20th century pointed to a quite different
policy, one of distributional indifference. Assuming (i)
convex preferences and production, and (ii) perfect information, efficiency is
unaffected by the initial distribution of wealth. In the absence of such nice
assumptions, of course, efficiency may well be affected.
With imperfect information, financial assets
usually determine one’s access to credit. In a new international data set
compiled for the World Bank by Deininger and Squire
(1996, 1997), an initial inequality of land holdings is found to be a major
barrier to growth. Of the 15 developing countries with Gini
coefficients on land in excess of 70 percent, the authors find that only two
grew at an annual rate of more than 2.5 percent over the period from 1960 to
1992.
The "contradiction" between
economic growth and redistribution, therefore, is often a conflict between
political interests, not a self-contradictory economic logic. The forces for
redistribution of land are usually hostile to free markets, as in the failed
Mexican ejidos or Soviet kolkhozes. The
elites favoring liberalization, on the other hand, can usually block any
substantial redistribution of wealth, as in the tepid land reforms of the
Postwar
The transitional regimes in
The success of these reforms is well-known:
Most Western economists concentrate on
getting the domestic prices "right" and see distributional issues
primarily as a political constraint, with a shadow price that should be
minimized. In this, of course, they have consistently applied neoclassical theory.
The Chinese and Vietnamese reformers, by contrast, had neither neoclassical nor
Marxist theory to guide their transition. As Benziger (forthcoming) puts it,
they were wise enough to realize that they did not know what they were doing.
Even the dramatic Chinese agricultural reforms were not really a "big
bang", but a series of piecemeal measures stretching out over nearly a
decade. They were, in the Chinese phrase, "crossing the stream by reaching
for the next stone."
It will be objected that the new governments
of CEE-FSU did not have political of such a slow inductive approach, and it is
true that the absence of a strong state has hurt the coherence of any
transition. But it is those countries of CEE with the strongest democratic movements pre-1989 that have built the most coherent states
post-1989, and this legacy could have been strengthened. The new governments of
CEE-FSU were in a position to deny compensation to the old "owners"
of land and capital, and thrown their economies open to the population’s
enthusiastic, if naive, free market embrace. And like the post-communist
regimes of
Instead, most of the new political leaders
chose the quieter, more familiar, and more personally lucrative path of
"insider" privatization, ceding assets to existing management and
workers. Vaclav Klaus, the recently fallen Czech
prime minister, stood virtually alone in his bold mix of redistribution with laissez-faire.
Klaus’s stance recalled an earlier, heroic period of bourgeois virtue, one for
which many, East and West, seemed nostalgic. His "capital reform",
the mass distribution of equity through vouchers, was the closest approximation
to the East Asian land reforms. Klaus (1995) explicitly justified this
redistribution as creating mass support for privatization.
But the redistribution of equity is not so simple as the redistribution of land, and Klaus was not
so austerely liberal as he seemed. State banks controlled the mutual funds in
which most Czechs placed their newly minted vouchers, and these proved
reluctant to liquidate "their" former state industries. An unsustainable
current account deficit, insider-trading, and banking scandals were the result,
and these finally brought down the Klaus government. Many analysts now blame
Klaus’s debacle on his egalitarian distribution of Czech vouchers.
There is no doubt that a broader distribution
of capital assets makes oversight and control more difficult. But this is an
issue that is far from settled within the mature market economies, as is clear
from debates around the power of institutional investors in the
Any review of Czech voucherization
must first of all acknowledge the impressive gains in political stability.
Earle et. al. (1997) use a 1996 survey
to show that the majority of Czech citizens who retained and reinvested their
original voucher shares were far more likely to express "strong
support" for the economic reforms, and overwhelmingly more likely to
oppose price controls, than the minority who had sold their vouchers
immediately for cash. One must question the direction of causality here, but
the broad appeal of the Czech voucher scheme makes it unsuitable as a screening
device for committed liberals. Over 80 percent of citizens were still holding
some of their original vouchers by early 1996, and
over 50 percent still held them all (Earle et. al. 1997, p. 44).
This broad political legitimacy, and what was
the longest-surviving government in CEE until its recent fall, made the
But in addition to this remarkable support
for reform, the Czech share redistribution has been accompanied by (i) admirable growth, (ii) low unemployment by OECD
standards, and (iii) astonishingly low inequality.
Growth: GDP per capita growth rates adjusted for purchasing
power are available from the CIA (1996) for 1993 through 1995. Czech growth
averaged 3.7 percent in these years, with
Unemployment: The projected unemployment of the
Inequality: The World
Bank inequality data of Deininger and Squiles (1996) show the
Ranking income distributions simply in terms
of Gini coefficients cannot be justified in terms of
any concave welfare function, as is well-known (Atkinson 1970). Nevertheless,
the relatively slow rise of the Czech Gini, when
combined with its steady economic growth, means that the overwhelming majority
in the
Although Czech growth is likely to fall in
1998, the performance of the past four years is impressive. Whether this
momentum can be regained is now very much in question. But in any case, the goals
of Czech macroeconomic policy -- restructuring without the demand shock of mass
unemployment – are probably impossible without their corollary, the massive
redistribution of assets.
Why should macroeconomic success be linked to
redistribution? In addition to the broader access to credit made possible by
broadly distributed financial assets, as in developing country land reform,
there are other issues specific to "capital reform." The problems of
oversight have been mentioned, but there are also efficiency gains from
diversification and liquidity. Capital markets need the risk-reduction and
liquidity that can only be achieved by portfolios that are both diversified and
widely held, as opposed to holdings that are highly concentrated and limited to
a few insider owners.
While failing enterprises were propped up for
too long in the
That market imperfections determine the most
efficient distribution of rights and liabilities is the starting point for the
microeconomic analysis of property rights. The Law and Economics school has
seen the common law as "an attempt to increase the value of [a] resource
by assigning property rights to those parties ... in whose hands the rights are
most valuable" when transactions costs preclude their efficient transfer
(Posner 1972, pp. 17-18). A similar research program has, until recently, not
been directed at the most fundamental fact of property, the distribution of
wealth itself. If financial markets are assumed to have no serious transaction
costs, then the question of an efficient distribution of wealth never arises.
Classic liberals like Jeremy Bentham and John Stuart Mill knew better: distribution
matters. Real markets "care" about the distribution of assets, risks,
and information. In the laboratory of capitalism’s most recent revolutions,
Mill’s proposition is being tested: for liberal property relations to flourish,
property is best distributed liberally.
References
Adelman, Irma and Sherman Robinson, Income Distribution
Policy in Developing Countries: a Case Study of Korea, Oxford, World Bank,
Oxford University Press, 1978.
Atkinson, Anthony B., "On the
Measurement of Inequality", Journal of Economic Theory, 2, 3,
September, 1970.
Benziger, Vincent, "Can China’s
Gradualist Reform Strategy Be Applied in
CIA, Handbook of International Economic
Statistics, Table 10, "Real Gross Domestic Product Per Capita
Growth", Washington, US Government Printing Office, 1996. website: http://www.odci.gov/cia/publications/hies96/c/c_3.htm.
Commander, Simon, Andrei
Tolstopiatenko and Ruslan Yemtsov (1997) "Channels of Redistribution: Inequality
and Poverty in the Russian Transition," prepared for the "Conference
on Inequality and Poverty in Transition Economies," EBRD,
Deininger, Klaus and Lyn Squire, "Economic Growth and
Income Inequality: Reexamining the Links", Finance & Development,
34, 1, March 1997.
_________________________,
"A New Data Set Measuring Income Inequality," World Bank Economic
Review 10, 3, 1996, pp. 565-591.
The data set itself is available online at
http://www.worldbank.org/html/prdmg/grthweb/datasets.htm
Done, Kevin, "Foreign Investment: Need
to Build on Early Success," Survey on the
Earle, John S., Scott G. Gehlback,
Zuzana Saková, and Jiri Vecernik, "Mass
Privatization, Distributive Politics, and Popular Support for Reform in the
Czech Republic", Working Paper No. 121, Stockholm Institute of Transition
Economics and East European Economics (SITE), 1997.
Feige, Edgar L., "Perestroika and Socialist
Privatization: What is To Be Done? And How?", Comparative
Economic Studies, 32, 3, Fall, 1990.
Frydman, Roman, Adnrzej Rapaczynski et. al., The
Privatization Process in
Klaus, Vaclav,
"Opening Address to the 10th Annual Congress of the European
Economic Association in
Kuo, Shirley W.Y., Gustav Ranis
and John C. Fei, The Taiwan Success Story, Rapid
Growth with Improved Income Distribution in the Republic of China, 1952-1979,
Boulder, Colorado, Westview Press, 1981.
Mill, John Stuart (1848) Principles
of Political Economy, and Chapters on Socialism, edited and with an
introduction by Jonathan Riley,
OECD, OECD Economic Outlook No. 61,
Paris, OECD, June, 1997.
Posner, Richard, Economic Analysis of the
Law,
Riley, Jonathan, "Introduction" to Principles
of Political Economy, and Chapters on Socialism, by John Stuart Mill,
Oxford, Oxford University Press, 1994.
Roemer, John E., A Future for Socialism.
Sachs, Jeffrey and Wing Thye Woo, "
Schmidt, Klaus M., "The Political
Economy of Mass Privatization and the Risk of Expropriation", Discussion
Paper No. 1542,