Scientific and Engineering Workers: Education Supplies, Occupational Demands

A shorter version appears in Engineering Management Conference, 2002 (IEMC '02), vol. 2, pp: 544-549: http://ieeexplore.ieee.org/xpls/abs_all.jsp?arnumber=1038493&tag=1

 

James Stodder, Lally School of Management and Technology

Rensselaer Polytechnic Institute at Hartford

275 Windsor Street, Hartford, CT 06120-2991, USA, stoddj@rpi.edu


 

   Abstract:  Recent studies by the National Science Foundation document the shortage of qualified scientific and engineering workers in the US.   Because the demand for such workers is relatively insensitive to salaries, there is an emerging consensus that, rather than further subsidizing demand (and salaries), the US needs to subsidize supply.  This paper argues that with regard to the Associate and level degrees for Engineers and Post-graduate degrees for Scientists, this consensus may be mistaken. A new data set compiled for this study relates educational supply to occupational demand through associated job "clusters" within 47 US states and Washington, DC.  It finds that Post-graduate degrees in the Sciences are highly responsive to research spending, while Associate degrees in Engineering are highly responsive to salary -- much more responsive than demand.  It follows that demand targeted to the appropriate incentive and degree level will be met with an elastic (responsive) supply.   Such a policy would moderate salary inequalities, largely driven by demand for highly skilled workers.  Across these states, the ratio between scientific-engineering graduate versus high-school graduate salaries is closely correlated with measures of overall wage inequality.

I.                 Introduction

Many economic commentators have expressed concern over shortages of qualified scientific and engineering (S&E) workers.  This has been the subject of national studies by the National Science Foundation [14] and on state levels as well, for example in the Connecticut Employment and Training Commission [3]. The fact of these skill shortages is not difficult to document, but the best policy response is a question of real controversy.

 

A widely-discussed essay by Paul Romer [15], a leading figure in the economics of technological change, argues that the supply response of American higher education is not only inadequate, but "perverse" -- in the sense of withholding supply just as demand is rising. His thesis is that university politics have constrained Science and Engineering departments from adequately expanding their student enrollments, pushing them to instead over-invest in 'quality' and scholarly research.  

 

   The present paper will not address that controversial thesis.  Two points of Romer's article that will be discussed, however, are his claims that:

·       The educational supply of US-born scientific and engineering workers is highly inelastic (insensitive) to salary, substantially less elastic than industry demand.

·       Because of this supply inelasticity, efforts to recruit more scientific and engineering talent by building up demand are destined to yield much higher salaries, but little in the way of higher supplies.  Government and private industry should look more to directly stimulating supply. (See also Mincer [12].)

 

While not questioning Romer's conclusions on a nationwide labor-market basis, I find that these conclusions do not apply on the state or regional level within the US, and do not hold for particular sectors of scientific and engineering workers.  

 

   The present study finds that in the Sciences, Bachelor's and Post-Graduate degrees show more supply than demand response from R&D expenditures.  In the broad Engineering and Electrical Engineering specialties, by contrast, the salary elasticity for Associate degree supply is much greater than that for industrial demand.  Thus, the supply of S&E workers is more market sensitive than demand at these degree levels and for these incentives.  Increased market demand, if it can be closely targeted to these degree levels and rewards, is likely to meet with an encouraging supply response. 

   High supply elasticities suggest that subsidies for salaries or R&D, if explicitly tied to early in-state career choices, could be highly productive.  Such subsidies are a demand side "quick fix" -- calling forth greater supply, not through deep overhauls of academic structures, but by targeted market subsidies.  There are other implications of this study that argue in the same direction -- for directing demand more on the more basic end of professional qualifications, to Associate degrees and short-term certificates:

·       Many studies, for example the Battelle report [3], stress the need to expand business input into the education process, to craft educational outcomes more for industry uses.  Such inputs are best concentrated on the earlier degree end of the higher educational process, where industry links are already strong and where outcomes are more rapidly achieved.

·       Comparisons or benchmarking of leading research states, such as California, Maryland, Illinois, and Virginia, suggest their educational programs focus more resources toward the Associate degree and Certificate levels [3].

·       Some richer states lag far behind in the provision of Associate degrees.  Connecticut, for example, with the highest income per capita in the US, provided no Associate degrees in the Sciences in 1996-97. This argues again for expanding the resources for these programs, and refocusing business demand and involvement in these fields.

·       This study finds that the gaps between unskilled (high-school diploma only) wages and the wages in these professional degree areas correlate strongly with the overall inequality of incomes.  An expansion in Associate and certificate programs -- as opposed to more resources for the highest degrees -- would tend to moderate these wage gaps.  The existence of a large wage gap also suggests that state resources are there to expand the more basic degrees.

 

   The findings of this study show that something can be done about expanding educational supply in the short term, before tackling reform of the deeply embedded and complex structures of academia (tenure, research focus, etc.)  Rather than contradicting Romer's thesis, the present study can be seen as a partial qualification, but also a confirmation of his basic argument.  It is a qualification inasmuch as it shows that the market insensitivity of the US higher education does not hold everywhere for the supply of S&E workers.  But it is a confirmation in that it finds

  • for Post-graduate degrees in the basic sciences, supply is sensitive to research expenditures rather than to salary increases, thus confirming the research focus Romer cites.
  • for Bachelors' degrees in engineering, the educational supply does appear "perverse," reacting to salary increases with fewer, not more degrees produced.
  • that the supply of engineers is most sensitive to salary pressure where Romer would predict -- far from the ethos of the great research universities, in the Associate degree programs.  Students in programs at the Associate and Certificate levels already have the shortest time-to-market, so we would expect to be more closely linked to regional demands.  

 

   These supply elasticities have clear policy implications.  Wage and research-expenditure elasticities for the supplies of S&E workers at the appropriate levels -- Post-graduate for the Sciences, and Associate for Engineering -- are found to be several times higher than the demand elasticities.  This implies that industry demands targeted to these degree levels, perhaps with provisions for continuing education, will meet with a robust supply response.

II. Four Educational/Occupational Clusters

 Many different sorts of academic training are used for many sorts of jobs.  How do we decide what these are, and thereby measure educational supply and occupational demand?  Unlike the UK and many other West European countries [7], the US has no nationwide database of occupations sorted by comparable levels of skill -- the US sorting of Occupational Employment Statistics (OES) is merely by industrial area [5]. The lack of such a skills-based occupational listing is more than just an academic concern.  Numerous empirical studies in the US and several different European countries show that educational mismatches -- employees who are inadequately trained or "overeducated" for their jobs -- are widespread and have significantly lowered the return to education in terms of wages and productivity [11].

 

To minimize this loss, and to help students plan their path from school to work, the state of Connecticut's Department of Labor has spent many years constructing its own grouping of Occupational Cluster [6] relating educational supplies and occupational demands. Lacking any comparable nationwide mapping, I will use these cluster definitions, and assume that these clusters are similar in every state. Supporting this assumption, I can show that the basic patterns of supply and demand within the US and Connecticut clusters are highly similar.  That is, within each cluster, the state and the national vector of demand for different occupational specialties are correlated, as are their vectors of supply for different academic degrees.  The correlation coefficients for these paired vectors are significant at the 5 percent level or better.  For five of the six series examined, the correlation coefficient is significant at 0.1 percent.  These state by state clusters -- drawn from sources [1], [5], [6], and [13] -- allow us to tie together, and then estimate, educational supplies and occupational demands.

 

The first grouping is the Sciences Cluster, containing the following occupational descriptions:

Table 1. Sciences Cluster

 

Biological Scientists

Chemists, Except Biochemists

Geologists, Geophysicists, and Oceanographers

Physicists and Astronomers

 

 

In Table 2., Engineering is a Macro-Cluster, or "cluster of clusters," with the following sub-clusters. One of its component clusters, Electrical Engineering, will be expanded below in Table 3.:

 

 

 

Table 2. Engineering Macro-Cluster

 

Sub-Cluster Titles

Electrical Engineering/Technology

Mechanical Engineering/Technology

Industrial Engineering/Technology

Civil Engineering/Technology

Architecture

Metallurgical Engineering/Technology

Chemical Engineering/Technology

Other Engineering Specialties

 

Table 3. Electrical Engineering/Technology Cluster

 

Computer Engineers

Electrical and Electronic Engineering Technicians and Technologists

Electrical and Electronic Engineers

Engineering, Mathematical, and Natural Sciences Managers

 

 

A full description of these clusters and their occupational and educational components is provided in

 

the Appendix, using national and state data.  Constructing these clusters from the various data sets is a fairly tedious process.  Nonetheless, if it shows the practicality of constructing a consistent national data set of educational supplies and occupational demands, it will constitute the main value of this paper.

III. Estimates of Supply and Demand

In the salary data from the OES [5] and ALMIS [1] data bases, there are only averages within each occupational specialty, rather than salaries at hiring.  Such offer prices would be the obvious focus for an analysis of supply and demand.  Instead, I use average salaries, weighted by the demand for new workers in particular occupations within each cluster.   These "hiring-weighted averages" were in all cases slightly below these overall averages -- as one would hope for entry level positions.

 

 

 

 A.  Supply and Demand for Employees in the Sciences

Demand estimates for the Sciences are given in Table 4. The dependent variable is the proportion of new openings among scientific occupations in 1996-97.  Demand and supply did show sensitivity to a variable that may be influenced by policy -- R&D spending as a portion of Gross State Product (GSP). In what follows, I will compare "elasticities" (sensitivities) of these R&D terms on the demand and supply sides.

Table 4: Scientists Demanded (All Degree Levels) Across US States, 1996-97

 

Dependent Variable: (DEMAND)

Job Openings in Sciences as Portion of Total Scientific Employment

                EQUATION (#)

(1)

(2)

R-squared

0.2588

0.2457

Adjusted

R-squared

0.1705

0.2122

F-statistic

2.9328

7.3293

 

 

 

Variables

 

Coefficient Estimates

t-statistics

Constant

0.032251

0.024423

 

1.677

5.781

 

 

 

State Personal Income

1.21E-08

 

0.022

 

 

Average Salary Science

-2.48E-07

 

-0.635

 

 

Science as Portion of Total State Employment

1.07164

 

0.791

 

 

 

R&D/GSP

0.200316

0.193474

 

1.491

1.823

 

 

 

Growth of GSP

0.313144

0.283168

 

2.986

3.015

 

Note: (Applies to all subsequent tables.):  T-stats. in italics.  T-stat. is above a critical level when underlined as dashed, single, or double, for a 15%, 10%, or 5% level of statistical significance, respectively.  There are 48 State Observations, plus DC.  All data are from 1996-1997.

 

In Tables 5 and 6 below, I give the supply-side estimates for Bachelors' and Post-Graduate degrees in the Sciences, as a portion of the total workforce. (The results of the regressions on the supply of Associate Degrees were not highly significant, and are not reproduced here.)  Although the R-squared is low, the R&D/GSP term is highly significant.

 

   Note that any problem separately estimating the supply and demand equations -- the well known "identification problem" of econometric analysis -- does not arise in our case.  The large gaps between state supplies and demands are in this sense fortuitous.  The proportion of students supplied and employees demanded are not only quite different, they are even given different denominators in our estimates -- that of the total State Employment and total cluster employment, respectively.

 

Table 5. Scientists Supplied (Bachelor's) Across US States, 1996-97

 

Dependent Variable: (SUPPLY)

Bachelor's Degrees in Sciences,

as Portion of Total State Employment

 

 

 

 

EQUATION (#)

(1)

(2)

(3)

R-squared

0.1218

0.0971

0.0736

Adjusted R-squared

0.0173

0.0355

0.0324

F-statistic

1.1653

1.5772

1.7873

 

 

 

 

Variables

 

Coefficient Estimates

t-statistics

Constant

9.31E-04

6.31E-04

5.69E-04

 

3.200

8.521

12.165

 

 

 

 

State Personal Income

-4.02E-09

 

 

 

-0.479

 

 

 

 

 

 

Average Salary Science

-5.53E-09

 

 

 

-0.935

 

 

 

 

 

 

Science Employment as Portion State Employment

 

-0.017812

 

-0.028922

 

-0.025419

 

-0.869

-1.644

-1.468

 

 

 

 

R&D/GSP

4.30E-03

3.25E-03

2.82805E-03

 

2.114

1.838

1.638

 

 

 

 

Growth of GSP

-1.30E-03

-1.57E-03

 

 

-0.816

-1.070

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Table 6:  Scientists Supplied (Post-Graduate) Across US States, 1996-97

Dependent Variable: (SUPPLY)

Post Graduate Degrees in Natural Sciences as Portion of Total State Employment

                           EQUATION (#)

(1)

(2)

(3)

R-squared

0.178541

0.1710

0.172709

Adjusted R-squared

0.080749

0.1341

0.116303

F-statistic

1.82571

4.6405

3.06188

 

 

 

 

Variables

 

Coefficient Estimates

t-statistics

Constant

5.30E-05

6.091E-05 

4.75E-05

 

0.939

6.853

1.055

 

 

 

 

State Personal Income

-3.22E-10

 

 

 

-0.198

 

 

 

 

 

 

Average Salary Science

5.13E-10

 

3.26E-10

 

0.446

 

0.303

 

 

 

 

Science Employment as

Portion State Employment

 

1.98E-03

 

 2.881E-03

 

2.41E-03

 

0.498

0.876

0.660

 

 

 

 

R&D/GSP

7.75E-04

7.91E-04  

7.40E-04

 

1.963

2.411

1.988

 

 

 

 

Growth of GSP

-1.66E-04

 

 

 

-0.539

 

 

 

Table 6 uses the regressions in Tables 4-5 to calculate demand and supply elasticities for R&D.  The coefficient estimates taken from these tables are from those regressions with highest adjusted R-squareds.  All coefficients are significant at the 10 percent level or better.  (Elasticities in this paper will be estimated at the minimum, median, mean, and maximum state figures, unless otherwise noted.) 

 

   In Table 7 below, elasticity terms are all far less than 1.0, indicating that a 1 percent increase in the portion of GSP devoted to R&D would lead to much less than 1 percent increase in the demand or supply for science workers.

 

 

 

 

Table 7: Scientists: Supply & Demand Elasticity with respect to Proportion of GSP used as R&D

-- States with Minimum, Median, Mean, and Maximum Values for this Proportion

 

 

 

Minimum

(S. Dakota)

Median (Alabama)

Mean

(Virginia)

Maximum

(New Mexico)

Dependent Variable:

 

New Openings as % Total Science Employment in State

4.000%

6.047%

3.333%

6.885%

Independent Variable:

R&D/GSP

0.350%

1.590%

1.969%

6.690%

 

(a) Coefficient on Independent Variable

0.1935

0.1935

0.1935

0.1935

 

(b) Independent/Dependent Variable

0.0875

       0.2629

    0.5907

      0.9717

 

 

(a) x (b) = DEMAND ELASTICITY of R&D:

 

0.0169

 

0.0509

 

0.1143

 

0.1880

 

 

 

 

 

 

Dependent Variable:

 

Science Bachelor's Degrees as % Total State Employment

0.0740%

0.0541%

0.0744%

0.0482%

Independent Variable:

R&D/GSP

0.350%

1.59%

1.969%

6.690%

 

(a) Coefficient on Independent Variable

3.25E-03

3.25E-03

3.25E-03

3.25E-03

 

(b) Independent/Dependent Variable

4.730

29.385

26.478

138.851

 

 

(a) x (b) = SUPPLY ELASTICITY of R&D:

 

0.0154

 

0.0955

 

0.0861

 

0.4513

 

 

 

 

 

 

Dependent Variable:

 

Science Post-Grad Degrees as % Total State Employment

0.0129%

0.0067%

0.0084%

0.0149%

Independent Variable:

R&D/GSP

0.350%

1.59%

1.969%

6.690%

 

(a) Coefficient on Independent Variable

7.91E-04  

7.91E-04  

7.91E-04  

7.91E-04  

 

(b) Independent/Dependent Variable

27.20

      237.29

    234.64

      449.76

 

 

(a) x (b) = SUPPLY ELASTICITY of R&D:

 

0.0215

 

0.1875

 

0.1854

 

0.3553

 

 

   These estimated elasticities indicate that a 100 per cent increase of R&D expenditures in median expenditure Alabama -- from 1.59 to 3.18 per cent -- would be predicted to increase the demand for scientists by 5.09 percent -- from our data value of 130, to 137.   This same 100 percent increase in R&D would be predicted to proportionally increase the supply of science bachelor's degrees almost twice as much, by 9.55 percent -- from 969 to 1,062.  For post-graduate degrees in the sciences, the proportional increase would be twice as great again, by 18.75 per cent -- from 120 to 132 degrees yearly.  Note that the R&D elasticity estimates for post-graduate scientists in Table 7 are greater than the elasticities for Bachelors' degrees.  We will not see this pattern repeated: unlike the case with these graduate degrees in the Sciences, the lower the degree level in Engineering, the higher its supply response -- to salaries.  The fact that it is research rather than salary dollars that generate the high supply elasticities in Table 7 above, suggests that the motivation for scientists tends to be different than that for engineers.  It is reasonable to find scientists more motivated by the opportunity for original research, and with that motivation increasing with their degree level.

 

   There is one pattern of Table 7 that we will see repeated in all of our estimates to come, however --  supply sensitivity always trumps demand.  This dominance of supply elasticity runs counter to national surveys of the market for scientific and engineering workers [14], [15].     Despite the appearance of a contradiction, however, there is no logical inconsistency between these two sets of findings.  Because states can recruit potential science students from other states, it is reasonable to expect that the supply of science students for an individual state might well be more R&D-elastic than the supply of the nation as a whole.  Indeed, there could be zero supply elasticity for the nation as a whole, but high elasticities for individual states.

A.     Supply and Demand for Engineering

   Table 8. Engineers Demanded (All Degree Levels) Across US States, 1996-97  

Dependent Variable: DEMAND

Job Openings in Engineering as Portion  of Total Engineering Employment

                           EQUATION (#)

(1)

(2)

(3)

(4)

R-squared

0.5210

0.5101

0.4832

0.4768

Adjusted R-squared

0.4640

0.4645

0.4480

0.4411

F-statistic

9.1370

11.1923

13.7143

13.3662

Variables

 

Coefficient Estimates

t-statistics

Constant

0.043815

0.044364

0.046427

0.020584

 

2.633

2.669

2.760

2.217

 

 

 

 

 

State Personal Income

7.12E-07

6.73E-07

 

3.45E-07

 

1.617

1.535

 

0.856

 

 

 

 

 

Average Salary Engineering

-7.25E-07

-6.93E-07

-4.20E-07

 

 

-1.782

-1.709

-1.135

 

 

 

 

 

 

Engineering Employment as Portion

of Total State Employment

 

0.883958

 

0.677213

 

0.729484

 

0.433221

 

2.676

2.666

2.855

2.019

 

 

 

 

 

R&D/GSP

-0.113651

 

 

 

 

-0.979

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Growth of GSP

0.330154

0.332133

0.306848

0.346742

 

4.540

4.571

4.271

4.704

 

   In the remainder of this paper, we give Supply estimates only for the lower-level (and more elastic) degrees. In Table 8 above, demand estimates for Engineering show a significantly negative coefficient on average salary.  The coefficient on Personal Income is positive and somewhat significant, implying that wealthier states demand more engineering services.   The significant coefficient on salary will allow us to compare its supply and demand elasticities.  R&D spending across states does not appear a significant determinant of demand for engineers, as it was in the demand for scientists.  This finding also holds true for the supply estimates below.

 

   In Table 9 below, the estimates for Bachelor's degrees in Engineering give Salary a significantly negative coefficient.  This supports Romer's [15] claim that the academic supply of engineers is "perverse" -- granting fewer degrees as more are demanded.   None of the other terms is significant.

 

Table 9. Engineers Supplied (Bachelor's Degrees) across US States, 1996-97

 

Dependent Variable: SUPPLY

Bachelor's Degrees in Engineering, as Portion of Total State Employment

 

 

 

 

                                            EQUATION (#)

(1)

(2)

(3)

R-squared

0.1569

0.0971

0.0965

Adjusted R-squared

0.0565

0.0355

0.0564

F-statistic

1.5632

1.5773

2.4030

 

 

 

 

Variables

Coefficient Estimates  t-statistics

Constant

0.02464

0.022401

0.022402

 

4.181

4.034

4.078

 

 

 

 

State Personal Income

-7.82E-08

-2.53E-08

 

 

-0.501

-0.165

 

 

 

 

 

Average Salary Eng.

-2.58E-07

-2.60E-07

-2.71E-07

 

-1.789

-1.799

-2.166

 

 

 

 

Engineering Employment as Portion State Employment

 

0.064637

 

0.143679

 

0.142897

 

0.552

1.698

1.710

 

 

 

 

R&D/GSP

0.060139

 

 

 

1.463

 

 

 

 

 

 

Growth of GSP

-0.02254

 

 

 

-0.875

 

 

   In the next Table 10, the supply estimates for Associate's degrees in Engineering show personal income and hiring-weighted salary as the only significant terms.  And unlike the previous table for Bachelors' degrees, salary here has the expected positive sign.  But it is interesting that the supply of associate degrees is negatively related to the state's personal income.  Supplying engineers is apparently not something most wealthier states are inclined to do, at least at the Associate level.

 

Table 10. Engineers Supplied (Associate Degrees) across US States, 1996-97

 

Dependent Variable: SUPPLY

Associate Degrees in Engineering as Portion of Total State Employment

                  EQUATION ( #)

(1)

(2)

(3)

R-squared

0.1670

0.1473

0.1415

Adjusted R-squared

0.0679

0.0892

0.1033

F-statistic

1.6842

2.5340

3.7078

 

 

 

 

Variables

 

Coefficient Estimates

t-statistics

Constant

9.06E-03

5.43E-03

2.63E-03

 

0.838

0.545

0.310

 

 

 

 

State Personal Income

-7.66E-07

-7.11E-07

-7.03E-07

 

-2.676

-2.591

-2.585

 

 

 

 

Average Salary Eng. 

3.68E-07

4.03E-07

4.83E-07

 

1.390

1.559

2.275

 

 

 

 

Engineering Employment as

Portion State Employment

 

0.179309

 

0.083327

 

 

0.835

0.549

 

 

 

 

 

R&D/GSP

-0.020757

 

 

 

-0.275

 

 

 

 

 

 

Growth of GSP

-0.045596

 

 

 

-0.965

 

 

 

Using the coefficients on salary from Tables 8 and 10 with highest t-stats gives the values in Table 11. A 10 percent increase in Minnesota's hiring-weighted salary (from $50,849 to $55,934) results in a 5.75 percent fall in Total Engineering Demand, but a 22.7 percent rise in the supply of Associate Engineering degrees.  This means a fall from 2,454 to 2,313 in openings for engineers (a loss of 141), but a rise in supply of Associate Degrees from 11,402 to 13,990 (a gain of 2,588).

Table 11: Engineers: Supply & Demand Elasticities with respect to Average Hiring Salary 

-- States with Minimum, Median ≈ Mean, and Maximum Salary, 1996-97.

 

 

 

Minimum

(Montana)

Median Mean (Minnesota)

Maximum

(New Jersey)

Dependent Variable:

New Openings as % Total Engineering

Employment in State

4.099%

6.416%

3.995%

Independent Variable:

Hiring-Weighted Average Engineering Salary

 $   40,499

 $   50,849

 $         59,849

 

(a) Coefficient on Independent Variable

-7.25E-07

-7.25E-07

-7.25E-07

 

(b) Independent/Dependent Variable

    988,074

    792,569

       1,498,204

 

(a) x (b) = DEMAND ELASTICITY:

-0.716

-0.575

-1.086

 

 

 

 

 

Dependent Variable:

Engineering Associate Degrees as

% Total State Employment

0.509%

1.083%

0.964%

Independent Variable:

Hiring-Weighted Average Engineering Salary

 $   40,499

 $   50,849

 $         59,849

 

(a) Coefficient on Independent Variable

4.83E-07

4.83E-07

4.83E-07

 

(b) Independent/Dependent Variable

 7,951,176

 4,695,632

       6,206,406

 

(a) x (b) = SUPPLY ELASTICITY:

3.840

2.268

2.998

 

 B. Supply and Demand for Electrical Engineering Workers

   In the following estimate of Table 12, Electrical Engineering Demand is sensitive to salary.  State Personal Income is weighted positively for demand.  All other coefficients have the expected sign, except for R&D.  This was not significant, and so was dropped as likely collinear with Employment.

Table 12: Electrical Engineers Demanded (All Degrees) across US States, 1996-97

 

Dependent Variable: DEMAND

Job Openings in Electrical Engineering as Portion of Total EE Employment

                  EQUATION (#)

(1)

(2)

(3)

R-squared

0.4944

0.4436

0.325

Adjusted R-squared

0.4343

0.4056

0.295

F-statistic

8.2154

11.6918

10.819

Variables

Coefficient Estimates  t-statistics

Constant

0.047581

0.052971

0.071972

 

2.565

2.911

3.861

 

 

 

 

State Personal Income

7.83E-07

 

 

 

1.426

 

 

 

 

 

 

Average Salary EE

-8.34E-07

-5.64E-07

-8.11E-07

 

-2.027

-1.451

-1.956

 

 

 

 

EE Employment as Proportion

of Total State Employment

 

1.73988

 

1.32317

 

1.77094

 

3.161

3.454

4.590

 

 

 

 

R&D/GSP

-0.230401

 

 

 

-1.523

 

 

 

 

 

 

Growth of GSP

0.303377

0.283524

 

 

3.163

3.066

 

In the following regression on the supply of Associate Degrees, in Table 13, we again see supply negatively correlated with state income, and positively related to hiring weighted salary.   As before, the Associate level shows more salary sensitivity than higher level degrees (regressions not shown).

 

Table 13. Electrical Engineers Supplied (Associate Degrees) across US States, 1996-97

 

 Dependent Variable: SUPPLY

Associate Degrees in Electrical Engineering as Portion Total State Employment

   EQUATION (#)

(1)

(2)

(3)

R-squared

0.20868

0.19398

0.173

Adjusted R-squared

0.11447

0.13902

0.116

F-statistic

2.21512

3.52968

3.064

Variables

 

Coefficient Estimates

t-statistics

Constant

2.89E-04

2.07E-04

1.35E-04

 

1.236

0.979

0.666

 

 

 

 

State Personal Income

-2.15E-08

 

-1.91E-08

 

-3.113

 

-2.909

 

 

 

 

Average Salary EE

7.12E-09

7.52E-09

9.38E-09

 

1.372

1.479

1.935

EE Employment as Portion

of Total State Employment

 

9.26E-03

 

6.17E-03

 

 

1.335

1.405

 

 

 

 

 

R&D/GSP

-4.87E-04

-1.98E-08

1.18E-03

 

-0.255

-3.051

0.892

 

 

 

 

Growth of GSP

-1.06E-03

 

 

 

-0.873

 

 

 

   In Table 14, supply is about twice as elastic as demand.  A 10 percent increase in salary for mean-salary Maine (from $49,263 to $54,189) would cause an 8.07 percent fall in job openings (from 799 to 716) annually, but a 16.66 percent rise in Associate degrees supplied (from 121 to 141).  These findings on elasticity have clear policy implications: pushing inelastic demand along the more elastic supply curve would make it possible get more added output per extra dollar spent.

 

 

 

Table 14. Electrical Engineering, Elasticities with respect to Average Hiring Salary 

-- States with Minimum, Median, Mean, and Maximum Salary, 1996-97.

 

 

Minimum

(Montana)

Mean

(Maine)

Median

(New Mexico)

Maximum

(Idaho)

Dependent Variable:

New Openings as % Electrical Engineering Employment in State

4.138%

5.091%

6.026%

7.682%

Independent Variable:

Hiring-Weighted Average

Electrical Engineering Salary

 $38,669

 $49,263

 $49,599

 $58,970

 

(a) Coefficient on Independent Variable

-8.34E-07

-8.34E-07

-8.34E-07

-8.34E-07

 

(b) Independent/Dependent Variable

          934,504

       967,667

       823,059

       767,629

 

(a) x (b) = DEMAND ELASTICITY:

-0.779

-0.807

-0.686

-0.640

 

 

 

 

 

 

Dependent Variable:

Elect-Engineer Associate Degrees as % Total State Employment

1.86E-05

2.22E-04

2.68E-04

3.60E-04

Independent Variable:

Hiring-Weighted Average

Electrical Engineering Salary

 $38,669

 $ 49,263

 $49,599

 $58,970

 

(a) Coefficient on Independent Variable

7.52E-09

7.52E-09

7.52E-09

7.52E-09

 

(b) Independent/Dependent Variable

 2,082,090,992

221,541,164

184,801,732

 163,835,348

 

(a) x (b) = SUPPLY ELASTICITY:

15.657

1.666

1.390

1.232

 

III. Within-State Income Inequalities

There is no question that the demand for Engineering and Science workers is increasing in the advanced industrial countries [14].  This growing disparity of supply and demand has implications for disparities in income.  Thus most economists explain the large increase in US income inequality since the early '70s as driven largely by increased demand for technologically skilled workers [10].  

 

Fig. 1 tracks the correlation between two inequality ratios on a state by state basis.  The first is the ratio of mean household income to its median -- that household at the 50th percentile of the distribution. The second is the ratio between the salary of science professionals, and the salary of the average high-school graduate with no further education [4].  The Pearson correlation coefficient between these two series is 0.59, with a significance level of 0.1 percent. (Similar correlations between inequality rations can be shown for engineering as a whole, and for electrical engineering, where the significance level is always at most 5 percent.)

 

Correlations do not show the direction of causality, of course. There is, however, evidence that the distribution of skill influences the distribution of salaries.  Comparing Germany and the US, for example, a recent study finds that Germany's distribution of wages can be partly explained by its more equal distribution of skills.  The paper's estimates imply that if the Germany had a dispersion of skills as wide as that actually found in the US, German inequality (as measured by the standard deviation of its log-wages) would increase by 3.9 percent.  Similarly, if the US had a German dispersion of skills, its wage inequality would fall by 4.7 percent [8].  

 

IV. Conclusions, Implications

The evidence shows that for some scientific and engineering labor markets, educational supply may be more salary-elastic than industry demand.   In such cases, subsidizing demand rather than supply will provide more employees at reasonable cost in the shortest possible time.

 

Directly subsidizing supply yields a longer term increase the stock of human capital and reduction in skill differentials, with lags of up to a decade [12]. If short-term supply elasticity is low, there is evidence that investment in public education has a high long-term social return, and lessens income inequalities and skill premia [2], [9], [16].

 

The principal accomplishment of this paper may not be its economics, which is elementary, but rather its accounting -- which is tedious but necessary.  That the US, unlike several European countries, has no cluster-integrated nation-wide database of occupations [7] is a problem and an opportunity.   The "cluster" analysis presented here makes the case that there are substantial gains to constructing and analyzing such a data set.   This paper has only scratched the potential of this large database -- only for three educational/occupational clusters, and only for one year.  There are dozens of clusters yet to be defined, complied, and analyzed.

 

 

Fig. 1: Salary Ratios -- Science Bachelor's over High School Graduates, Mean over Median, by State  1996-97

 

Sources (all figures): OES database; Census tapes (DDB: PPINC*DDB(0), MDB: PPINC*DDB)


Figure 2: Salary Ratios: Engineer's Bachelor's Over High School Graduates, Mean Over Median, by State

Pearson Correlation Coefficient: 0.461 (p = 0.001)

Spearman's Rank Correlation:     0.419 (p = 0.003)

 

Figure 3: Salary Ratios: Elect. Engineer's Over High School Graduates, Mean Over Median, by State

Pearson Correlation Coefficient: 0.311 (p = 0.031)

Spearman's Rank Correlation:     0.315 (p = 0.029)

 

Sources: Same as previous Figure.

 

Acknowledgment: Support for this study was provided by the Connecticut Economic Resource Center, http://www.cerc.com.  The views expressed are the responsibility of the author alone.

 

Appendix: Five Data Sets Integrated, Four Clusters Examined

Note: The new integrated national data set assembled for this report is very extensive, with several thousand records in each of the five national data sets that were used to compile it. Data are only presented in their final extracted form here -- the form used for this report's calculations. The complete data set has been assembled into spreadsheet form, on CD-ROM, and is available from the author.

 

A.1 The Five Data Sets

Just as poor materials can undermine the best design, it is useless to do detailed empirical analysis with inadequate data. To understand the relation of educational supply and occupational demands, I am comparing

1)     Educational Program Completions and School Spending;

2)     Salaries of High-school Graduates;

3)     Occupational Demands;

4)     Wages in those Occupations; and

5)     Occupational Clusters, relating 1) and 3)

 

To construct the data set used for this paper, I have integrated 5 different data sets, no two of which were designed to be strictly comparable.

 

Looking at 1) data on educational supply, state-by-state comparability is excellent. The National Center for Educational Statistics (NCES) [13] offers the Integrated Post-secondary Education Data System (IPEDS) at nces.ed.gov/ipeds/.   This is a truly national source on completions, by program and level of degree awarded, going from the present back to the late 1980s. 

 

For 2) salaries of high-school graduates on a state-by-state level, census tapes [4] averaged for 1992-94 and 1995-97 were used, extracted via the "ferret" program at www.census.gov.

 

When one comes to the labor market data, large gaps begin to appear.  For estimates of 3) annual occupational demands, the source is ALMIS (American Labor Market Information System), almis.dws.state.ut.us/, [1].  This gives state employment levels for thousands of job descriptions.   However, several large industrial states (New York, Pennsylvania, and Michigan) do not provide ALMIS with their data, nor does Washington D.C.  These four data "holes" exist in everything that follows.

 

For 4) average occupational salaries, one must go to the Occupational Employment Statistics (OES) [5] page of the Bureau of Labor Statistics, stats.bls.gov/oeshome.htm.  These average salaries do not represent the salary at which new labor was hired, and are thus not strictly the wage component of labor demand.  In order to approximate this wage however; the occupational weightings used in the cluster were those of the annual demands listed by ALMIS [1], shown in 3) above.[1]   Using the actual demand weights for each cluster -- rather than un-weighted average salaries -- proved very important in getting reasonable results for the regression estimates. 

 

Finally, I come to the issue posed in 5) the appropriate clusters of Supply and Demand. Which educational programs and job descriptions should we fit together?  To answer this, I have used the Occupational Cluster definitions developed by the Connecticut State Department of Labor.  These Clusters are laid out a 1996 publication [6].  The most recent data available for all four data sets is based on the 1996-97 academic and fiscal year.

A.2 Four Clusters in Science and Engineering

A.2.1 Definition of the Science Cluster

I have broken out two "hard" sciences, the Physical Sciences and Life Sciences Cluster.  This reflects an emphasis on fundamental research, rather than on technical implementation.   The overlap of the OES, ALMIS and Connecticut DoL data sets allows a relatively limited focus, on just four occupational categories.  As defined by the Connecticut State Department of Labor, the Science Cluster is made up of the following component occupational clusters.  Note that the two series are highly correlated, at the 2 percent level of significance.

 

 Table A.1. Occupational Classifications of Sciences Cluster: OES [5], ALMIS [1], CT DoL [6], 1996-97

 

Cluster Code

OES Code

OES Title, OES

Almis, Connecticut DoL Title

US Demand

Connecticut Demand

1205

24308

Biological Scientists

 Biological scientists

2,640

190

1206

24105

Chemists, Except Biochemists

 Chemists

3,650

140

1206

24111

Geologists, Geophysicists, and Oceanographers

 Geologists, geophysicists, and oceanographers

1,710

20

1206

24102

Physicists and Astronomers

 Physicists and astronomers

380

10

 

 

 

ALMIS TOTAL DEMAND

8,380

360

 

 

 

Connecticut Dol Total Demand

500

 

 

 

Data Set Connecticut Coverage, ALMIS/ Connecticut DoL

72.0%

Pearson Correlation Coefficient, US and CT demands: 0.944 (p-value = 0.016)

 

The next order of business is to gather the occupations listed in the Connecticut Department of Labor (Connecticut DoL) definition of this macro-cluster [6] with those occupations listed in the national ALMIS database [1].  Overlap is not perfect.  In order to get data on wages; I have to then compare this national set with the occupations listed in the OES database [5].  The complete listing of the intersection of these three data sets in the Technology cluster, and their US and Connecticut job openings for 1996-97, is given in Table A.1.  Note that changes in the Cluster Code, the first column, are reflected in changes in the font color.

 

Notice also that whenever there is a discrepancy in the job titles -- apart from the mere capitalization of letters or ordering of titles -- the classification titles are underlined.  The left column shows the titles of the Bureau of Labor Statistics OES and its Occupational Classification Code (OCC) [5].  The right column shows those used by both ALMIS [1] and the Connecticut Department of Labor [6].  For the most part these offer little opportunity for confusion.

 

The final rows compare the Total Demand, or number of job openings in 1996-97, as accounted both by this merged data set, and by the Connecticut DoL set [6].  We see that about 64% of the job openings accounted for by Connecticut have been preserved in the transition to a national system.   A similar percentage of Data Set Coverage will be seen in the other clusters to follow.  Some loss is unavoidable, until a nationally integrated data system for occupational demands is instituted.

 

Next we come to the CIP (Classification of Instructional Programs) Codes given by the national IPEDS (Integrated Post-secondary Data Set) [13].  Here, the codes used nationally and by Connecticut are identical.  Again, note at the bottom of Table A.2, that the structure of relative completions in the US and CT supply is highly similar, with a correlation coefficient significant at the 0.01 percent level.

 

Table A.2. Program Completions in Sciences cluster:  IPEDS [13] and Connecticut DoL [6], 1996-97

 

Cluster Code

CIP code

CIPTITLE

US Supply

CT Supply

1205

26.0101

Biology, General

53443

566

1205

26.0401

Cell Biology

478

13

1205

26.0402

Molecular Biology

1081

120

1205

26.0499

Cell and Molecular Biology, Other

1633

42

1205

26.0501

Microbiology/Bacteriology

3359

8

1205

26.0608

Neuroscience

578

21

1205

26.0616

Biotechnology Research

259

7

1205

26.0702

Entomology

389

 

1205

26.0704

Pathology, Human and Animal

166

12

1205

26.0705

Pharmacology, Human and Animal

426

7

1205

26.9999

Biological Sciences/Life Sciences, Other

2234

6

1205

30.0101

Biological and Physical Sciences

9186

 

1205

51.1307

Medical Immunology

44

10

1205

51.1308

Medical Microbiology

208

0

1206

40.0101

Physical Sciences, General

1491

22

1206

40.0601

Geology

4182

21

1206

40.0603

Geophysics and Seismology

177

 

1206

40.0699

Geological and Related Sciences, Other

302

17

1206

40.0703

Earth and Planetary Sciences

829

19

1206

40.9999

Physical Sciences, Other

594

68

 

 

IPEDS Total Completions

81059

959

 

 

Connecticut DoL Total** Completions       1503

 

 

Data set Coverage, IPEDS Connecticut /Connecticut DoL   63.81%

Pearson Correlation Coefficient, US and CT supplies: 0.991 (p-value = 0.000)

 

 

A.2.2 Definition of Engineering Cluster

 

This is a broad macro-cluster, of eight component clusters:

 

Table A.3.  ENGINEERING MACRO-CLUSTER, Connecticut Department of Labor [6]

 

Sub-Cluster Titles

Cluster Titles

Electrical Engineering/Technology

1101

Mechanical Engineering/Technology

1102

Industrial Engineering/Technology

1103

Civil Engineering/Technology

1104

Architecture

1105

Metallurgical Engineering/Technology

1106

Chemical Engineering/Technology

1107

Other Engineering Specialties

1108

 

Dozens of job descriptions are spread over these clusters.  Of these, the following jobs are covered jointly by our first three data sets.  Note at the bottom of Table A.3, that the structure of relative occupational demand in the US and CT supply is highly similar, with a correlation coefficient significant at the 0.01 percent level.

 

Table A.4. Occupational Classifications of Engineering Cluster:

OES [5], ALMIS [1], CT DoL [6], 1996-97

 

Cluster code

OES code

OES Title

Almis Title

US Demand

CT  Demand

1101

22.127

Computer Engineers

 Computer engineers

25,000

340

1101

22.505

Electrical and Electronic Engineering Technicians and Technologists

 Electrical and electronics engineers

19,720

210

1101

22.126

Electrical and Electronic Engineers

 Electrical and electronic technicians and technologists

12,130

180

1101*

13.017*

Engineering, Mathematical, and Natural Sciences Managers

 Engineering, science, and computer systems managers

6,840

69

1102

22.102

Aeronautical and Astronautical Engineers

 Aeronautical and astronautical engineers

1,010

40

1102

22.138

Marine Engineers

Marine Engineers

320

10

1102

22.135

Mechanical Engineers

 Mechanical engineers

8,130

180

1102

22.117

Nuclear Engineers

 Nuclear engineers

430

10

1103*

13.017*

Engineering, Mathematical, and Natural Sciences Managers

 Engineering, science, and computer systems managers

6,840

69

1103

22.128

Industrial Engineers, Except Safety

 Industrial engineers, except safety engineers

3,890

70

1104

22.121

Civil Engineers, Including Traffic

 Civil engineers, including traffic engineers

8,170

100

1104*

13.017*

Engineering, Mathematical, and Natural Sciences Managers

 Engineering, science, and computer systems managers

4,560

46

1104

22.521

Surveying and Mapping Technicians

 Surveyors

2,010

20

1105

22.302

Architects, Except Landscape and Marine

 Architects, except landscape and marine

3,920

40

1105

22.308

Landscape Architects

 Landscape architects

710

10

1106

22.105

Metallurgists and Metallurgical, Ceramic, and Materials Engineers

 Metallurgists and metallurgical, ceramic, and materials engineers

610

20

1107

22.114

Chemical Engineers

 Chemical engineers

2,190

20

 

 

 

ALMIS Total Demand

106,910

1,434

 

 

 

Connecticut DoL Total     1,960

 

 

 

Data Set Connecticut Coverage, ALMIS/Connecticut DoL   73.2%

Pearson Correlation Coefficient, US and CT supplies: 0.997 (p-value = 0.000)

 

(*) Note:   Engineering, Mathematical, and Natural Sciences Managers (OES Code 13017) are accounted as allocated between Clusters 1101, 1103 and 1104, Electrical Engineering, Industrial Engineering, and Civil Engineering, respectively.  They are allocated in proportions of 0.3, 0.3 and 0.2, again, respectively.  (The remaining 0.2 is allocated to Cluster 1503, Mathematical Specialties.)  This is the allocation used by the Connecticut Department of Labor.

The educational specialties within this cluster are extremely diverse.  Over seventy listings are given in the Connecticut DoL tables, although, as with the labor demand data above, the final rows of Table 6 show that 73% of the DoL listings are captured by the IPEDS [13] data.  Again, the correlation between the two series is significant at 0.01 percent.

Table A.5. Program Completions in Engineering cluster:  IPEDS [13], Connecticut DoL [6], 1996-97

 

Cluster code

CIP code

CIPTITLE

US Supply

CT Supply

1101

14.0901

Computer Engineering

3939

59

1101

14.1001

Electrical, Electronics & Communication

21976

194

1101

15.0301

Computer Engineering Tech./Technician

4033

81

1101

15.0303

Elec., Electronic & Comm. Engin. Tech.

17230

131

1101

15.0304

Laser and Optical Tech./Technician

208

1

1101

15.0399

Electrical & Electronic Engin.-Related Tech

9383

57

1101

15.0402

Computer Main. Tech./Technician

3907

188

1102

14.0201

Aerospace, Aeronautical and Astronautic

2177

 

1102

14.0301

Agricultural Engineering

901

 

1102

14.1101

Engineering Mechanics

344

 

1102

14.1901

Mechanical Engineering

18341

208

1102

14.2201

Naval Architecture & Marine Engineering

330

7

1102

14.2301

Nuclear Engineering

462

 

1102

14.2401

Ocean Engineering

273

1

1102

15.0403

Electromechanical Tech./Technician

1629

 

1102

15.0404

Instrumentation Tech./Technician

817

 

1102

15.0405

Robotics Tech./Technician

731

 

1102

15.0801

Aeronautical & Aerospace Engineering Tec

751

1

1102

15.0803

Automotive Engineering Tech./Technician

1124

30

1102

15.0805

Mechanical Engineering/Mechanical Tech.

3033

63

1102

15.0899

Mechanical Engineering-Related Tech, Oth

1040

2

1102

41.0204

Industrial Radiologic Tech./Technician

22

 

1102

41.0205

Nuclear/Nuclear Power Tech./Technician

102

9

1103

14.1701

Industrial/Manufacturing Engineering

6147

78

1103

14.3001

Engineering/Industrial Management

1204

 

1103

15.0603

Industrial/Manufacturing Tech/Technician

4392

35

1103

15.0699

Industrial Product. Technol./Techn, Oth.

1241

120

1104

14.0801

Civil Engineering, General

14982

94

1104

15.0201

Civil Engineering/Civil Tech./Technician

1976

8

1104

15.1001

Construction/Building Tech./Technician

2116

7

1104

15.1102

Surveying

574

 

1105

4.0201

Architecture

6726

72

1105

4.0401

Architectural Environmental Design

771

2

1105

4.0501

Interior Architecture

1047

21

1105

4.0601

Landscape Architecture

1259

12

1105

4.9999

Architecture and Related Programs, Other

771

7

1105

15.0101

Architectural Engineering Techno/Tech

2014

26

1106

14.1801

Material Engineering

1329

2

1106

14.2001

Metallurgical Engineering

424

13

1106

15.0611

Metallurgical Tech./Technician

87

 

1107

14.0701

Chemical Engineering

8511

42

1107

41.0301

Chemical Tech./Technician

579

6

1108

14.0101

Engineering, General

5005

22

1108

14.0501

Bioengineering & Biomedical Engineering

1645

9

1108

14.1201

Engineering Physics

393

19

1108

14.1301

Engineering Science

670

27

1108

14.1401

Environmental/Environmental Health Engin

2050

25

1108

14.2701

Systems Engineering

1008

1

1108

14.2901

Engineering Design

15

 

1108

14.3101

Materials Science

329

5

1108

14.3201

Polymer/Plastics Engineering

133

 

1108

14.9999

Engineering, Other

2341

32

 

 

IPEDS Total Completions:       162,492

Connecticut DoL Total** Completions:

Data Set Coverage, Connecticut Total/ Connecticut DoL:

     1,717

1,365

126%

Pearson Correlation Coefficient, US and CT demands: 0.991 (p-value = 0.000)

 

 

 

A.2.3 Definition of Electrical Engineering Cluster 

Electrical Engineering has generated particular interest as the area of engineering most closely associated with computer and related technologies.  The overlap of our three labor market data sets shows the following demand count, with the correlation between the national and state series significant at 0.1 percent.

Table A.6. Occupational Classifications - Electrical Engineering Cluster:

OES [5], ALMIS [1], CT DoL [6], 1996-97

 

Cluster Code

OES Code

OES Title

Almis Title

US Demand

CT Demand

1101

22.127

Computer Engineers

 Computer engineers

25,000

340

1101

22.505

Electrical and Electronic Engineering Technicians and Technologists

 Electrical and electronic technicians and technologists

12,130

180

1101

22.126

Electrical and Electronic Engineers

 Electrical and electronics engineers

19,720

210

1101

13.017

Engineering, Mathematical, and Natural Sciences Managers

 Engineering, science, and computer systems managers

22,800

230

 

 

 

ALMIS Total Demand

79,650

960

 

 

 

Connecticut DoL Total  Demand

880

 

 

 

Data Set Connecticut Coverage ALMIS/Connecticut DoL

109.1%

Pearson Correlation Coefficient, US and CT demands: 0.994 (p-value = 0.001)

 

The data on program completions are as follow, with the correlation between the US and CT series significant at 0.01 percent.

Table A.7. Program Completions in Electrical Engineering cluster: 

IPEDS [13]Connecticut DoL [6], 1996-97

 

Cluster code

CIP

Code

CIP TITLE

 US Supply

CT Supply

1101

14.0901

Computer Engineering

           3,939

            59

1101

14.1001

Electrical, Electronics and Communication Engineering

         21,976

          194

1101

15.0301

Computer Engineering Tech./Technician

           4,033

            81

1101

15.0303

Electrcial, Electronic and Communications Engin. Tech./Technician

         17,230

          131

1101

15.0304

Laser and Optical Tech./Technician

              208

              1

1101

15.0399

Electrical and Electronic Engineering-Related Technol./Technician

           9,383

            57

1101

15.0402

Computer Main. Tech./Technician

           3,907

          188

 

 

IPEDS Total Completions

         60,676

          711

 

 

Connecticut DoL Total** Completions

          384

 

 

Data Set Connecticut Coverage, IPEDS/Connecticut DoL

185.16%

Pearson Correlation Coefficient, US and CT supplies: 0.955 (p-value = 0.000)

 

In this assembly of multi-state supply and demand data, I have based our definition of clusters on the extensive research and practical experience of the Connecticut Department of Labor [6].   How comprehensive is this new multi-state data set?  To compare it to the individual data sets of all 50 states is neither practical nor important at this point.  What I have done is to compare its coverage with the published records of the DoL. 

 

To summarize, the multi-state data set I have assembled covers about 2/3 of the occupational listing and labor demand categories of the Connecticut DoL data [6].  When it comes to the school completions data, however, the new data set's coverage often has better coverage (over 100%) compared to data used by the Connecticut DoL in assembling its clusters.  This greater coverage of the IPEDS [13] may result from its data having been updated more recently.

 

REFERENCES

[1] ALMIS (American Labor Market Information System),  http://almis.dws.state.ut.us/.

[2] R.J. Barro, "Human capital and growth in cross-country regressions," Swedish Econ. Pol. Rev., Vol. 6, pp. 237-277, Autumn 1999.

[3] Battelle Consultants, "An information technology workforce strategy for the state of Connecticut," Connecticut Employment & Training Comm., Dec. 2000.

[4] Bureau of the Census, tapes on state high school grad. rates, via "ferret" extraction tool, http://www.census.gov.

[5] Bureau of Labor Statistics, Occupational Employment Statistics (OES), http://stats.bls.gov/oeshome.htm.

[6] Connecticut State Dept. Labor, "Making the future yours: a comparison of job openings and education and training graduates," 1996.

[7] P. Elias and A. McKnight, "Skill measurement in official statistics: recent developments in the UK and the rest of Europe," Oxford Econ. Paps., Vol. 3, pp. 508-540, 2001.

[8] R. Freeman and R. Shettkat, "Skill compression, wage differenttials, and employment: Germany vs. the US," Oxford Econ. Paps., Vol. 3, pp. 582-603, 2001.

[9] C. Goldin and L. Katz "America's graduation from high school: the evolution and spread of secondary schooling in the twentieth century", J. Econ. History, Vol. 58, pp. 345-374, June 1998.

[10] J. Greenwood, "The third industrial revolution: technology, productivity, and income equality," Fed. Resrv. Bank Cleveland, Econ. Review, Vol. 35, 1999.

[11] J. Hartog "Over-education and earnings: where are we, where should we go?" Econ. Educ. Rev., Vol. 19, pp. 131-147, April 2000.

[12] Jacob Mincer, "Investments in U.S. education and training as supply responses," Rsch. Labor Econ., Vol. 17; pp. 277-304, 1998.

[13] Natl. Center for Educational Statistics, "Integrated post-secondary education data system," http://nces.ed.gov/ipeds/.

[14] Natl. Science Fnd., "Science and Engineering indicators - 2000," Arlington, www.nsf.gov/sbe/srs/seind00/start.htm.

[15] P. Romer, "Should the government subsidize the supply or demand in the market for scientists and engineers?," Natl. Bur. Econ. Rsch., Working Paper No. 7723, 1999.

[16] K. Sylwester, "Can education expenditures reduce income inequality?" Econ. Educ. Rev., Vol.21, pp.43-

52, Feb. 2002.

 

A shorter version of this paper was printed in an IEEE conference volume.

Search for author “Stodder” at the conference site:

 http://ieeexplore.ieee.org/xpl/tocresult.jsp?isnumber=22258

“Scientific-technical workers: education supplies, occupational demands”

Engineering Management Conference, 2002. IEMC '02. 2002 IEEE International

Volume: 2

Digital Object Identifier: 10.1109/IEMC.2002.1038493

Publication Year: 2002 , Page(s): 544-549 vol.2

 



[1] The occupations listed have slightly different names in OES [5] and in ALMIS [1].   Comparability is not aided, furthermore, by the fact that OES uses the numerical Occupational Classification Code (OCC), while ALMIS does not.  In all cases surveyed, however, a clear title match was possible.   Comparisons of particular ALMIS and OES occupational titles can be seen in the cluster definitions that follow.

 

** In the Connecticut Department of Labor (CT DoL) Tables [6], the Total count on program completions is given without graduate degrees.  (The number of graduate degrees is listed separately.)  The Connecticut DoL does this because many of those completing graduate programs are part time students, and already employed in their field. For purposes of widest comparison here, the number of all degrees was used to compute the Connecticut DoL Total**, as given above.  In this paper's statistical work, I will break down total completions both ways, with and without graduate degrees.